"What human beings want is not oil or coal, or even gasoline
or electricity per se, but the services that those energy sources
provide."--Reddy et al (2000), Energy and Social
Issues, in 'World Energy Assessment: energy and the challenge of
sustainablility', UNDP
I don't know much about biology and chemistry and about many
things. And with the flawed Bush's alternative policy to the Kyoto's
treaty to contain global warming, we must all try to understand what
is happening not only to our so called static (or statistical)
economy of the Free Market but also to our ecological (or dynamic)
economy of our lives. Therefore, I am going to provide the
explanation of global warming by referring to some excerpts from the
outstanding book "Business Dynamics" by Professor John Sterman of
MIT. Also, I am going to refer to the conceptual flaw of using the
'cost-benefit' method for making decisions on environment protection
policies by including excerpts from the intelligent paper "Pricing
the Priceless: Cost-Benefit Analysis of Environmental Protection" by
Lisa Heinzerling and Frank Ackerman of Georgetown University Law
Center.
Excerpts from: System Dynamics in Action: Global Warming.
Section 7.2 of Business Dynamics, by John D. Sterman (2000)
...The earth is a warm mass surrounded by the cold of space
and like such masses emits so-called black body radiation whose
frequency distribution and intensity depends on its surface
temperature. The warmer the mass, the more energy it radiates.
Incoming solar energy warms the earth. As it warms, more energy is
radiated back into space. The temperature rises until the earth is
just warm enough for the energy radiated back to space to balance
the incoming solar energy.
The amount of energy radiated back into space depends on the
composition of the atmosphere. Greenhouse gases (GHGs) such as
carbon dioxide and methane trap some of the energy radiated by the
earth, instead of allowing it to escape into space. Thus an increase
in GHGs causes the earth to warm... Natural processes have caused
the concentration of carbon dioxide (CO2) in the
atmosphere to fluctuate significantly over geological time, and
surface temperatures have fluctuated with it. Human activity has now
reached a scale where it can affect these [natural] processes...
Atmospheric concentrations of CO2 and other GHGs
including nitrous oxide (N2O), methane (CH4),
chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs), hydrofluorocarbons (HFCs),
perfluorinated carbons (PFCs), and others have been growing
exponentially, with concentrations of CO2, N2O,
and CH4 up by 30, 15, and 145%, respectively, since
1800.Mean global surface temperatures are about 0.5 to 10C
warmer today. By comparison, the mean global temperature during the
last ice age, when sheets of ice 1000 feet thick covered much of the
northern hemisphere, was about 50C colder than today...
In 1995, the UN sponsored Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
(IPCC) concluded that global warming was indeed occurring, and that
human activity was responsible, stating "The balance of evidence
suggests a discernible human influence on climate" (IPCC 1996).
Through the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC)
various nations are negotiating limits to GHG emissions, though
compliance remains elusive...
Excerpt from Pricing the Priceless: Cost-Benefit Analysis
of Environmental Protection. Executive Summary. By Lisa Heinzerling
and Frank Ackerman
In recent years the use of "cost-benefit" analysis to set
environmental standards has attracted a large and high-profile group
of supporters. According to its advocates, cost-benefit analysis
offers a way of achieving superior environmental results at a lower
overall cost to society than other available approaches. This view
is mistaken. Cost-benefit analysis is a deeply flawed method that
repeatedly leads to biased and misleading results... In order to
assess the pros and cons of any particular regulatory standard,
cost-benefit analysis seeks to translate all relevant considerations
into monetary terms... The costs and (particularly) the benefits of
regulation often will be realized in the future; in such cases the
numeric estimates of costs and benefits are "discounted," i.e.
treated as equivalent to smaller amounts of money today.
Proponents of cost-benefit analysis make two basic arguments
in its favor. First, use of cost-benefit analysis ostensibly leads
to more "efficient" allocation of society's resources by better
identifying which potential regulatory actions are worth undertaking
and in what fashion. Advocates of cost-benefit analysis also contend
that this method produces more objective and more transparent
government decision-making by making more explicit the assumptions
and methods underlying regulatory actions... In fact, cost-benefit
analysis is incapable of delivering what it promises. First,
cost-benefit analysis cannot produce more efficient decisions
because the process of reducing life, health, and the natural world
to monetary values is inherently flawed... Cost-benefit analysis
also ignores the fact that citizens are concerned about risks to
their families and others as well as themselves, ignores the fact
that market decisions are generally very different from political
decisions, and ignores the incomparability of many different types
of risks to human life. The kinds of problems which arise in
attempting to define the value of human life in monetary terms also
arise in evaluating the benefits of protecting human health and the
environment in general.
Second, the use of discounting systematically and improperly
downgrades the importance of environmental regulation... discounting
tends to trivialize long-term environmental risks, minimizing the
very real threat our society faces from potential catastrophes and
irreversible environmental harms, such as those posed by global
warming and nuclear waste.
Third, cost-benefit analysis ignores the question of who
suffers as a result of environmental problems and, therefore,
threatens to reinforce existing patterns of economic and social
inequality...
Finally, cost-benefit analysis fails to produce the greater
objectivity and transparency promised by its proponents...
Real-world examples of cost-benefit analysis demonstrate the
strange lengths to which this flawed method can be taken. For
example, the consulting group Arthur D. Little, in a study for the
Czech Republic, concluded that encouraging smoking among Czech
citizens was beneficial to the government because it caused citizens
to die earlier and thus reduced government expenditures on pensions,
housing, and health care... cost-benefit analysis should be rejected
as a tool for evaluating environmentally protective regulation.
References
Business Dynamics- New system dynamics text book with CD-ROM
models and simulation software, J. Spencer Standish Professor of
Management, Director, MIT System Dynamics Group http://web.mit.edu/jsterman/www/BusDyn2.html
Pricing the Priceless: Cost-Benefit Analysis of Environmental
Protection. By Lisa Heinzerling and Frank Ackerman, Georgetown
Environmental Law and Policy Institute, Georgetown University Law
Center, January/February 2002 http://www.globalpolicy.org/socecon/envronmt/2002/CostBen2002.htm
Sites related to Global Warming: Climate Ark - The Premier
Climate Change & Renewable Energy Portal http://www.climateark.org/vital/impacts.htm
International Institute for Sustainable Development http://www.iisd.org/climatechange.htm
A Primer on Climate Change http://www.ec.gc.ca/climate/primer/sec-6.htm
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change http://www.ipcc.ch/
Canada's Greenhouse Gas Emissions http://www.nrcan.gc.ca/communications/cc2000/html/ghg_emissions.html
United Nations Framework Convention Climate Change http://unfccc.int/issues/index.html
|